![]() |
Participants At The “Celebration Of Life” Tribute For Chinua
Achebe In Awka, Anambra State Capital City
|
Wednesday, 22 May 2013
Photonews: Awka Pays Tribute To Chinua Achebe
News Release: MEND Suspends “Operation Barbarossa”
In
spite of several provocative and careless utterances by so-called South-South
elders led by Chief Edwin K Clark testing our resolve to carry out our planned
attacks on mosques and other related agencies of religious intolerance, the
intervention of well meaning Nigerians, religious bodies and the Nigerian
government’s recent show of sincerity with the order to release from detention
women, children, relatives and suspected Boko Haram members giving room for
genuine dialogue has been taking into serious consideration. We have also
heeded to the appeal from Mr Henry Okah and Mr. Kingsley Kuku, Special Adviser
to the President on Niger Delta Affairs.
To
these effects, the Movement for the Emancipation of the Niger Delta (M.E.N.D)
hereby announces the suspension of “Operation Barbarossa” which was to have
commenced from Friday, May 31, 2013, with immediate effect.
We
use this opportunity to call for the release of Henry Okah and others in detention
over the October 01, 2010, twin car bomb blast.
Speech: The Outlook For Fiscal Adjustment In Advanced Economies
![]() |
Mr. Carlo Cottarelli |
By Carlo
Cottarelli
Thank
you very much Adam for these nice words and for inviting me here. Today, I am
going to talk about a topic that has been keeping us busy for the last few
years and, as the title of my presentation suggests, will keep us busy for a
few more years, as, whether we like it or not, high public debt is going to be
with us for quite some time.
My
presentation will be based on our Fiscal Monitor, the IMF publication that we
introduced in 2010 to monitor fiscal developments around the world. I will
address four main questions
· First, how bad is the fiscal position in advanced economies? It
is pretty bad. Indeed, one could argue that, in many countries, it has never
been as bad as it is today.
· Second, what are the risks arising from the poor state of the
fiscal accounts in these countries? High for some of them. For others, the
immediate risks are not so high. But the situation would be difficult for all
in the long run, in the absence of further adjustment.
· Third, what is the appropriate strategy to address these fiscal
challenges? We continue to believe that fiscal adjustment should proceed, but
at a moderate speed and with a medium-term orientation, at least for countries
not subject to severe market pressures.
· Fourth, is this strategy of gradual fiscal adjustment working? I
will argue that it is, although major challenges still lie ahead.
One
issue that I will not discuss, for brevity, is the merit of what we can call
non-orthodox approaches to fiscal adjustment, like inflation or debt
restructuring, but I will be happy to take questions on this issue, and I am
sure there will be some.
So, let
me start with the first question: How bad is the fiscal position in advanced
economies?
Some of
you may have already seen this figure depicting the public debt to GDP ratio
for advanced economies since 1880. The ratio is currently at about 110 percent,
close to the peak reached during the Second World War. Public debt is also at a
peak with respect to private sector wealth, although the available time series
here is much shorter.
But the
outlook is actually worse than at the end of the Second World War for four
reasons:
· First, most of the fiscal adjustment then consisted of cuts in
military spending, which are easier to implement from a political perspective.
· Second, spending for pension and health care will be on the rise
over the coming decades, and by several percentage points of GDP. So countries
in need of fiscal adjustment will have, so to speak, to swim against the tide
of rising spending pressures.
· Third, long-term growth prospects are not great, which is bad as
growth erodes the debt-to-GDP ratio. Long-term growth will be lower than in the
post-war period when the labor force was rising rapidly. We now project a
decline in the labor force in advanced economies.
· Fourth, financial repression in the 1950s and 1960s, in the form
of interest rate ceilings and investment requirements in government paper,
facilitated the financing of public debt. These restrictions are no longer in
place.
Not all
advanced economies, however, are equally in trouble. Leaving aside some smaller
countries, fiscal problems are particularly severe in 10 countries, where debt
ratios are high and still rising: United States, Japan, UK and seven euro area
members (France, Italy, Spain, Belgium, Greece, Portugal and Ireland). They
represent about 40 percent of world GDP so what happens to their fiscal policy
has major implications for the rest of the world.
Let’s
have a closer look at these countries. This figure will show on the horizontal
axis the increase in the debt to GDP ratio since 2007 and on the vertical axis
the level of the deficit to GDP ratio also since 2007. I am going to show you
first the other advanced economies: these economies started, on average, with a
small surplus in 2007; deficits and debt increased in 2008 and 2009, but since
then things have improved rapidly with declining deficits and essentially no
increase in debt ratios. This contrasts with the behavior of our ten countries.
Here is the average, with deficit and debt rising sharply in 2008, 2009 and
2010, and with declining deficit but still rising debt ratios since then. And
here is the behavior of individual countries which clearly belong to a
different class.
The
magnitude of the fiscal challenges faced in the years ahead by these countries
can be illustrated by our standard long-term adjustment scenarios, which focus
on the degree of fiscal tightening that will be needed in the future to lower
public debt from the current level to, say, 60-80 percent by 2030. Let’s
clarify by showing you one of these scenarios. In our scenarios the adjustment
is gradual. Here you see the primary balance of the government—that is the
difference between revenues and non-interest spending—improving gradually by
2020 and then stabilizing at the required level for another ten years. The debt
ratio keeps rising for a while, but then declines, hitting its target, 60
percent of GDP by 2030. We run these scenarios for each country. Before showing
you the results it is important to recognize that the difficulty of implementing
this adjustment can be measured by two indicators: first, the size of the
adjustment following 2013; second, the level of the primary balance that will
have to be maintained over time.
The
results of these scenarios will be reported in this chart: on the horizontal
axis you find the first indicator—the needed improvement in the primary balance
over the next seven years—while on the vertical axis you will see the level of
the primary balance that will have to be maintained until 2030. Each country is
represented by a set of points, not a single point, because we run scenarios
that vary in terms of the specific debt target, 60 or 80 percent, and the
assumptions on interest rates and growth, which are key determinants of debt
dynamics. The legend tells you exactly what the assumptions are for each
scenario.
The
cross country ranking is fairly clear: France and Belgium are in a relatively
stronger position, with required adjustment of about 2 percentage points of GDP
after 2013 and targets for the primary balance levels of 2-3 percentage points
of GDP. Most other countries are in this central and more challenging pack,
with two exceptions: Italy, whose “solar system” centers around the vertical
axis, implying that not much further adjustment is needed, but at a higher
level than other countries, implying that the level of the primary surplus it
needs to maintain for many years is very high; and Japan, which is the clear
outlier.
So,
there are important differences across countries, but running these large fiscal
surpluses over time is likely to be challenging for all of them. So one
question could be: what happens if instead there is no further adjustment and
public debt remains as high as it is now?
In
other words: what are the risks arising from the poor state of the fiscal
accounts?
Concern
about high public debt has focused on two very different aspects.
The
first one is the effect of high public debt on long-run economic growth. This
concern is most often linked to the names of Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff,
who found an historical correlation between debt exceeding 90 percent and low
growth. Leaving aside the issue of the recently found problem in their
spreadsheets—I am sure you have heard about this—the focus on the Reinhart and
Rogoff results has been excessive, in my view, from the beginning. First, their
work did not take into account that the correlation between growth and debt can
run from low growth to high debt and not vice versa. Second, their results were
based simply on statistical averages rather than on econometric estimates of
how high public debt affects growth.
However,
several econometric studies have focused on the relationship between debt and
growth and, with one exception (the Panizza and Presbitero paper), find
evidence of a relationship that likely goes from high debt to low growth.
Without getting into much detail, this chart does show a negative relationship
between debt levels and growth, noting that here growth is growth in the five
years following each debt level observation, thus at least suggesting a
causality that goes from high debt to low growth.
The
second reason why we should be worried about high public debt relates to the
risk of a fiscal crisis. In theory, the risk of fiscal crises caused, in
particular, by self-fulfilling expectations is high for high debt countries
because, when public debt is high, an increase in interest rates can really
make a difference between what is sustainable and what is not sustainable.
In
practice we do see that high debt does matter for the perception of risk. In
this chart you see for each country the deficit and debt ratio in 2012 and each
country is represented by a balloon whole size is proportional to the size of
the CDS spread: as you can seen, almost all large balloons fall in this area
which corresponds to a combination of high deficit and high debt: so, large
fiscal imbalances do matter for the perception of risk. They are not a
sufficient condition to be in trouble—you see many small balloons even for some
high debt countries—but they are at least a necessary condition to be in
trouble.
Of
course, as I said, some high debt countries are still enjoying record low
interest rates, like US, UK and Japan. This benign market attitude can be
explained at least in part by the surge in base money and the consequent
monetization of public debt that we have observed since 2007, as this figure shows
for our three countries.
This
surge in base money has not been inflationary because it has been matched by an
increased demand for base money. Over time, as conditions normalize, the share
of public debt financed by printing money will have to decline—the so called
exit strategy problem—which will tend to raise interest rates on government
paper. While this normalization of interest rates is expected to take place in
the context of higher growth, the net impact on the differential between
interest rate and growth, which is what matters for the dynamics of the debt
ratio, is likely to be positive, thus putting pressure on high debt countries.
Altogether,
maintaining public debt at high levels over the long run does not seem to be a
great idea. There is probably broad consensus about this, although there are
clearly differences on why high public debt is bad, on exactly how high it
needs to be before bad things happen, and on the urgency of the case for
lowering public debt.
Let me
therefore come to the third question of my presentation. What is the
appropriate strategy to address these fiscal challenges, including in terms of
urgency of the fiscal adjustment? In this austerity debate, we have the view of
the fiscal doves, who argue that there is no immediate fiscal problem and that
there is even room to expand, and the view of the fiscal hawks who believe that
the price to be paid for committing the sin of fiscal profligacy will be very
high. Our position since 2010, when Olivier Blanchard and I published a blog
post entitled “Ten Commandments for Fiscal Adjustment in Advanced Economies,”
is an intermediate one between these extreme positions.
Let me
summarize the four main elements of our position:
· First, for countries that are not under market pressure, fiscal
adjustment should proceed at a moderate pace within a medium-term fiscal
adjustment plan to enhance credibility.
· Second, these medium-term plans should be defined in cyclically
adjusted terms so as to allow the automatic stabilizers to operate if growth
differs from initial expectations.
· Third, countries under market pressure should proceed more
rapidly but also for these there is a speed limit beyond which fiscal
adjustment can be counterproductive.
· Finally, this fiscal strategy should be supported by structural
reform to boost medium-term growth and by relaxed monetary condition to cushion
the contractionary effect of fiscal tightening and to reduce the risk of
self-fulfilling fiscal crises.
We have
often argued that this position is based on the recognition that there are
costs if you tighten too much—essentially not enough short-term growth—and
there are costs if you do not tighten enough—arising, for example, from the
risk of a fiscal crisis. However, this, per se, does not justify taking an
intermediate position. What is critical, instead, is the existence of
nonlinearities that arise from taking extreme positions. In other words, the
cost of excessive austerity and of excessive profligacy can be particularly
high. In this case the total cost function has a minimum for intermediate
policies, as illustrated in this chart.
Let’s
look more closely at the costs of fiscal austerity and the costs of fiscal
profligacy. As discussed in a recent blog by Olivier Blanchard and Daniel
Leigh, the costs of fiscal tightening are now high because:
· First, fiscal multipliers are particularly large now reflecting
the downward inflexibility of nominal interest rates, the difficulties banks
have in granting credit, particularly in Europe, the large share of households
that are credit rationed, and the fact that, in a recession, cuts in demand
affect more real output than prices, a point discussed in the April 2012 Fiscal
Monitor. These factors are likely to operate to produce relatively higher
multipliers regardless of the composition of the fiscal adjustment, whether it
is done on the revenue side or on the spending side. Governments should still
calibrate the composition of the adjustment to minimize its short-term and
long-term growth impact—for example by avoiding cutting investment spending and
avoiding tax increases in countries where tax rates are already high. But it
would be unrealistic, in the current circumstances, to hope to engineer an
expansionary fiscal contraction focused on spending cuts of the kind discussed
by Giavazzi and Pagano in their famous 1990 paper because the mechanisms that
would stimulate growth following a fiscal tightening a drop in interest rates
or an exchange rate depreciation—would not operate now for most countries in
need of fiscal adjustment.
· The second reason why fiscal tightening has a particularly high
cost now is that the cost of an output loss is larger when the economy is
already growing slowly. We tend to dislike extremes (indeed that is the basis
for running countercyclical policies). We have some evidence that markets
dislike extremes too. Laura Jaramillo and I wrote a short note on the effect of
large fiscal tightening on interest rates. The results are illustrated in this
figure, showing that when the multiplier is sufficiently high and the
tightening sufficiently strong, interest rates may rise, not decline, following
a fiscal tightening, This happens because markets get worried about growth as
well as about the rise in the debt to GDP ratio that may accompany the fiscal
tightening when GDP declines, an effect noted in a recent paper by Luc Eyraud
and Anke Weber, two economists from the IMF’s Fiscal Affairs Department.
· Finally, there may be higher than usual hysteresis effect, as
noted by Brad de Long and Larry Summers, because of the length of the current
recession and the related high number of long-term unemployed.
Let’s
now look at the other side, the costs arising from the fiscal profligacy. I
already mentioned that these arise from the long-term growth effects of high
public debt and the risk of a fiscal crisis. Let me therefore just underscore
three issues regarding these costs.
First,
the risk of fiscal crises could be eliminated if there were a commitment
technology that would make sure that fiscal tightening took place later, in
good times. In this case promising fiscal adjustment would be enough.
Unfortunately such a technology does not exist. Things are made more difficult
by three factors. First, in the past advanced economies did not use their good
times to lower public debt which was, it is worth recalling, already at record
levels in 2007 before the crisis. Second, this fiscal twist (expand now,
tighten later) was already danced in 2008-09: so countries that had promised to
tighten later are supposed to tighten now. Third, gaining credibility by
implementing long-term pension and health care reforms—which affect long term
fiscal trends at low cost for output today—may not help much because,
unfortunately, interest rates do not seem to be much correlated to pension and health
care spending increases. Altogether, just promising fiscal adjustment is
unlikely to be enough.
Second
issue related to the cost of fiscal profligacy: we tend to underestimate the
cost of fiscal crises before they occur for two reasons. First, fiscal crises
are typically nonlinear events that are not easily detectable before they
happen in full swing. The timing of these crises is highly uncertain—as we
often say, it is a situation of Knightian uncertainty. Second, these fiscal
crises do involve large output losses but these costs are observed only after
the crisis materializes and so we tend to focus on the observable costs of
fiscal austerity. Altogether, there may be a tendency to ignore these costs.
Yet, one can expect that the risk of a confidence crisis becomes increasingly
large the larger the fiscal imbalances, which is an important source of
nonlinearity.
Third
issue: the risk of turmoil on the government paper market is not the same for
all countries. A surge in interest rates due to an increased risk premium,
which would be quite dangerous in the presence of high debt, is a very unlikely
event for countries like the United States or Japan given their strong investor
bases. It would be a “black swan.” But, black swan events do happen and their
costs can be pretty high. It is a tail risk that cannot be ignored and that
will persist as long as public debt remains high. When debt is high even a
modest increase in interest rates has severe effects, particularly in
countries, like Japan, where banks have invested massively in fixed yield
government paper. Again, I am talking about low probability events, but their
cost, if they materialize, would be huge.
The
bottom line is that, faced with high costs from extreme solutions—too much
austerity and too much profligacy—the most sensible course of action is to
proceed with fiscal adjustment at a relatively moderate pace, of course taking
into account that for countries that are already under market pressure the risk
of a fiscal crisis is of course larger, which calls for a faster adjustment.
Given
this approach, which countries are moving at the appropriate speed, and which
are not? The Fiscal Monitor identifies some cases where fiscal adjustment is
not proceeding in line with our prescriptions:
· On the one hand Japan is moving too slowly. Its deficit remains
stuck at about 9 percentage points of GDP and its debt keeps rising fast. Japan
has become an outlier in terms of fiscal performance, as evidenced by this
three-dimensional chart showing the deficit, the primary deficit and the net
debt ratio for 2013. It was not an outlier in 2010, as you can see. Japan needs
to define quickly a medium-term adjustment plan to lower its public debt. It
will have to go well beyond the currently envisaged adjustment measures, such
as the increase in VAT from 5 to 10 percent.
· On the other hand, the US is adjusting too rapidly this year.
The fiscal cliff has been avoided but the fiscal tightening this year will
still be the largest one in the last three decades. A more moderate pace of
adjustment, in the context of a medium-term adjustment plan, would be
preferable.
· Finally, a few European countries that have suffered from
chronically weak private sector demand could at least consider smoothing the
pace of the adjustment. But in most European countries the underlying pace of
adjustment is appropriate in terms of measures. The main risk to avoid is
targeting headline deficits regardless of growth developments. In this respect,
we see more flexibility on the side of European institutions. While the
Stability and Growth Pact targets are still set in terms of headline figures,
these targets have been revised significantly over time, as illustrated by this
chart.
Let me
address the last question: is this strategy of steady fiscal adjustment working
and is it realistic to continue it for the future?
There
has been considerable progress since 2010 in fixing the fiscal accounts. Two
milestones will be reached in 2013. First, the average deficit of advanced
economies will be about half of what it was in 2009, from 9 percent of GDP to
little more than 4½ percent. Second the average debt ratio—weighted by GDP—will
stabilize, indeed it will slightly decline. So fiscal adjustment, while costly
in terms of output, is yielding some results.
There
is no doubt, however, that major challenges still lie ahead. Let’s go back to
the chart showing the additional adjustment needed for each country to bring
down debt to 60-80 percent of GDP by 2030. How challenging are these targets?
To answer, we have looked at what countries did in the past when they really
tried to lower their debt ratio. Most specifically, for each advanced economy
we have looked at highest primary surplus sustained over a ten-year period
during the last sixty years. This is the corresponding distribution which has a
median of 3¼ percent. We have also looked at the largest improvement in the
primary balance over a seven-year period (as in our scenarios countries still
have seven years ahead to complete the adjustment) following a three-year
period of adjustment (as countries have already been adjusting for about three
years, so they may feel some fatigue). And this is the distribution with a
median of about 5 percentage points of GDP. We have then used these
distributions to identify in our summary chart areas of increasing difficulty
corresponding to increasing quartiles of the distribution. So areas closer to
red are more difficult to achieve.
Most
countries are now to the left of this vertical line representing the median of
the distribution of seven-year fiscal improvements, implying an additional
required adjustment that is below the median of what was achieved when
countries in the past really tried hard. So not impossible, although obviously
still hard, as we are comparing the required adjustment with what were the best
past performances. Most countries are, however, above the median in terms of
primary surplus level which would have to be maintained over time. The bottom
line is that, while the required levels of primary surplus are now not out of
reach, maintaining those primary surpluses over time will require a special
effort.
But
will it be necessary to maintain a very large primary balance for such a long
time? Let me conclude with a note of optimism. I suspect that most investors
are more concerned about seeing the debt ratio put on a downward path than they
are about the speed with which the debt ratio declines. Once the debt is on a
downward trajectory, whether a certain debt target is achieved in 2025, 2030,
or 2040 is less important, particularly if fiscal institutions are strengthened
to ensure that fiscal plans are perceived as credible. If this occurs, real
interest rates may turn out to be lower than those that we assume in these
scenarios and countries will have some room to reduce their primary surplus
without disturbing the trend of falling debt ratios.
So, to
conclude, getting debt ratios back to where they need to be will remain a long
process, but hopefully it will not last from here to eternity.
Thank
you very much for your attention and you can find on our website more
information on the world’s fiscal accounts from our Fiscal Monitor. Thank you.
Released By IMF Communications Department
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)